A’Hearn, B. and U. Woitek. (2001). More international evidence on the historical properties of business cycles, Journal of Monetary Economics, 47, 321-346.
Altug, S. (1989). Time-to-build and aggregate fluctuations: some new evidence, International Economic Review, 30, 889-920.
Bencivenga, V. (1992). An econometric study of hours and output variation with preference shocks, International Economic Review, 33, 449471.
Bouakez, H., Cardia, E. and F. Ruge-Murcia (2005). Habit formation and the persistence of monetary shocks, Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1073-1088.
- Chari, V., Kehoe, P. and E. McGrattan (2007a). Are structural VARs with long-run restrictions useful in developing business cycle theory? Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Research Department Staff Report 364.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- Chari, V., Kehoe, P. and E. McGrattan (2007b). Business cycle accounting, Econometrica, 75, 781-836.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- Chib, S. and Greenberg, E. (1995). Understanding the MetropolisHastings algorithm, American Statistician, 49, 327-335.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Chib, S. and I. Jeliazkov (2001). Marginal likelihood from the Metropolis-Hastings output, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 96, 270-281.
Christiano, L. (1988). Why does inventory investment fluctuate so much? Journal of Monetary Economics, 21, 247-280.
Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M. and R. Vigfusson (2003). What happens after a technology shock? NBER Working Paper, 9819.
Cogley, T. and Nason, J. (1995). Output dynamics in real-business-cycle models, American Economic Review, 85, 492-511.
Cogley, T. and T. Sargent (2005). Drifts and Volatilities: Monetary Policies and Outcomes in the Post WWII US, Review of Economic, Dynamics, 8, 262-302.
- DeJong, D., Ingram, B. and C. Whiteman (2000a). Keynesian impulses versus Solow residuals: identifying sources of business cycle fluctuations, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 15, 311–329.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- DeJong, D., Ingram, B. and C. Whiteman (2000b). A Bayesian approach to dynamic macroeconomics, Journal of Econometrics, 98, 203-223.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Eichenbaum, M. (1991). Real business-cycle theory: wisdom or whimsy? Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 15, 607-626.
- FernaÃŒÂndez-Villaverde, J. and J. Rubio-RamıÌÂrez (2004), Comparing dynamic equilibrium models to data: a Bayesian approach, Journal of Econometrics, 123, 153–187.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- FernaÃŒÂndez-Villaverde, J. and J. Rubio-RamıÌÂrez (2005), Estimating dynamic equilibrium economies: linear versus nonlinear likelihood, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 20, 891-910.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Francis, N. and V. Ramey (2005). Is the technology-driven real business cycle hypothesis dead? Shocks and aggregate fluctuations revisited, Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1379-1399.
- GalıÌÂ, G. (1999). Technology, employment, and the business cycle: do technology shocks explain aggregate fluctuations?, American Economic Review, 89, 249-271.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
GalıÌÂ, J. and P. Rabanal (2005). Technology shocks and aggregate fluctuations: how well does the RBC model fit postwar U.S. data? NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2004, (ed) M. Gertler and K. Rogoff, 225-88, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
- Gelman, A., Roberts, G., and W. Gilks (1996). Efficient Metropolis jumping rules. In: Berger, J.O., Bernado, J.M., David, A.P., Smith, A.F.M. (Eds.), Bayesian Statistics, Vol. 5. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 599–607.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- Geweke (1992). Evaluating the accuracy of sampling-based approaches to the calculation of posterior moments. In: Bernardo, J.M., Berger, J.O., Dawid, A.P., Smith, A.F.M. (Eds.), Bayesian Statistics, Vol. 4. Oxford University Press, Oxford, 169–193 (with discussion).
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- Gordon, R. (2000). Interpreting the “one big wave†in U.S. long-term productivity growth, NBER Working Paper 7752, Cambridge, MA.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- Greenberg, E. (2008). Introduction to Bayesian Econometrics, Cambridge University Press, New York.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Hall, G. (1996). Overtime effort, and the propagation of business cycle shocks, Journal of Monetary Economics, 38, 139-160.
- Hamilton (1994). Time Series Analysis, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Hansen, G. (1985). Indivisible labor and the business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 16, 309-327.
- Harvey, A. (1992). Forecasting, Structural Time Series Models and the Kalman Filter, Cambridge University Press.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Ireland, P. (1997). A small structural, quarterly model for monetary policy evaluation. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 47,83-108.
- Ireland, P. (2001a). Money’s role in the monetary business cycle, NBER Working Paper 8115, Mass.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Ireland, P. (2001b). Sticky-price models of the business cycle: specification and stability, Journal of Monetary Economics, 47, 3-18.
Ireland, P. (2001c). Technology shocks and the business cycle: an empirical investigation, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 25, 703-719.
Ireland, P. (2002). Endogenous money or sticky prices? NBER Working Paper 9390, Cambridge, Mass.
Ireland, P. (2004). A method for taking models to the data, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 24, 1205-1226.
Ireland, P. (2008). Productivity and US macroeconomic performance: Interpreting the past and predicting the future with a two-sector real business cycle model, Review of Economic Dynamics, 11, 473-92.
Kim, J. (2000). Constructing and estimating a realistic optimizing model of monetary policy, Journal of Monetary Economics, 45, 329-359.
King, R., Plosser, C., and S. Rebelo (1988). Production, growth and business cycles: I. the basic neoclassical model model, Journal of Monetary Economics, 21, 195-232.
- Lütkepohl, H. (1991). Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis, Springer.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
McGrattan, E. (1994). The macroeconomic effects of distortionary taxation, Journal of Monetary Economics, 33, 573-601.
McGrattan, E., Rogerson, R. and R. Wright (1997). An equilibrium model of the business cycle with household production and fiscal policy, International Economic Review, 38, 267-290.
Nordhaus, W. (2004). Retrospective on the 1970s productivity slowdown, NBER Working Paper 10950.
- Priestley, M. (1981). Spectral Analysis and Time Series. Academic Press, London.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Primiceri, G. (2005). Time varying structural vector autoregressions and monetary policy, The Review of Economic Studies, 72, 821–852.
Ruge-Murcia, F. (2007). Methods to estimate dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 31, 2599-2636.
Sargent, T. (1989). Two models of measurements and the investment accelerator, Journal of Political Economy, 97, 251-287.
Schorfheide, F. (2000). Loss function-based evaluation of DSGE models, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 15, 645-670.
Sims, C. (1989). Models and their uses, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 71, 489-494.
Smets, F. and R. Wouters (2003). An estimated stochastic dynamic general equilibrium model for the euro area, Journal of the European Economic Association, 1, 1123-1175.
Stock, J. and M. Watston (1996). Evidence on structural instability in macroeconomic time series relations, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 14, 11-30.
Watson, M. (1993). Measures of fit for calibrated models, Journal of Political Economy, 101, 1011-41.