Abstract
Empirical evidence shows that low-income households spend a high share of their income on pollution-intensive goods. This fuels the concern that an environmental tax reform could be regressive. We employ a framework which accounts for the distributional effect of environmental taxes and the recycling of the revenues on both households and firms to quantify changes in the optimal tax structure and the equity impacts of an environmental tax reform. We characterize when an optimal environmental tax reform does not increase inequality, even if the tax system before the reform is optimal from a non-environmental point of view. If the tax system before the reform is calibrated to stylized data—and is thus non-optimal—we find that there is a large scope for inequality reduction, even if the government is restricted in its recycling options.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
We are only concerned with the (intra-generational) distribution between different households at a given point in time, since increased intra-generational inequality is one of the most commonly used arguments against environmental policy (Combet et al. 2010; Ekins 1999). For an article that considers both intra- and inter-generational distributional effects of environmental taxation see Jacobs and van der Ploeg (2010).
Sandmo (1975) called this principle the additivity property.
This contribution and related research is centered around the question whether the marginal cost of public funds equals unity or not. Kaplow (2004) was the first to argue that these are indeed equal to one, if Mirrleesian income taxes and optimal public good supply are set simultaneously. Jacobs and De Mooij (2015) extend Kaplow’s thesis to the case of Pigouvian taxes combined with optimal income distribution. This holds when uniform lump-sum transfers are available to the government, in which case there are no environmental double dividends possible.
Bovenberg and van der Ploeg (1994, 1996) use the terms “blue welfare” for the non-environmental welfare component, and “green welfare” for the welfare component that depends on the environmental quality, to make this important distinction. Bovenberg and van der Ploeg (1996) and Ligthart and van der Ploeg (1999), further decompose welfare in a red and a pink component which accrue to changes in public consumption and employment, respectively. Since we assume constant government spending and full employment, there are no effects on public consumption or employment in our model.
We use the Gini coefficient in non-environmental utility, see Sect. 2.3 for more details.
This means all equations laid out in Sect. 2 remain the same, but we add the constraint that \(L=0\).
While some kinds of inequality may indeed be detrimental for society, others motivate people to work harder, and can be beneficial (Marrero and Rodríguez 2013). However, there seems to be evidence that inequality itself can have a negative effect on efficiency (Berg et al. 2012; Kumhof et al. 2015). At least for this reason, assuming suboptimally high levels of inequality is thus a credible premise and inequality-reduction a frequent policy goal.
We refrain from displaying the results of revenue recycling through a combination of lump-sum transfers and non-linear income tax cuts, since it leads to the same outcome as the scenario with only non-linear income tax cuts. The reason for that is that the government uses all the environmental tax revenue to mitigate inequality in the income tax system and hence has no use for lump-sum transfers.
This concept is different, however, from the concept of the environmental double dividend in the sense of Goulder (1995) and Bovenberg (1999): In models with only one representative household such a (weak) dividend can occur, when recycling through income tax cuts is more efficient than lump-sum recycling. A strong double dividend, that is an increase in economic efficiency, can only occur with an inefficient pre-existing tax system. In our setting, there is also an increase in GDP (see Fig. 5, bottom) because the pre-existing income tax schedule creates an inefficient labor supply.
References
Ballard CL, Goddeeris JH, Kim SK (2005) Non-homothetic preferences and the non-environmental effects of environmental taxes. Int Tax Public Finance 12:115–130
Bento AM (2013) Equity impacts of environmental policy. Annu Rev Resour Econ 5(1):181–196
Bento AM, Goulder LH, Henry E, Jacobsen MR, Haefen RHV (2005) Distributional and efficiency impacts of gasoline taxes : an econometrically based multi-market study. Am Econ Rev 95(2):282–287
Berg A, Ostry JD, Zettelmeyer J (2012) What makes growth sustained? J Dev Econ 98(2):149–166
Bovenberg AL (1999) Green Tax reforms and the double dividend: an updated reader’s guide. Int Tax Public Finance 6:421–443
Bovenberg AL, van der Ploeg F (1994) Environmental policy, public finance and the labour market in a second-best world. J Public Econ 55(3):349–390
Bovenberg AL, van der Ploeg F (1996) Optimal taxation, public goods and environmental policy with involuntary unemployment. J Public Econ 62:59–83
CBO (2013) The distribution of household income and federal taxes, 2010. Congress of the United States—Congressional Budget Office 4613 (December)
Chiroleu-Assouline M, Fodha M (2014) From regressive pollution taxes to progressive environmental tax reforms. Eur Econ Rev 69:126–142
Combet E, Ghersi F, Hourcade J-C, Théry D (2010) Carbon tax and equity the importance of policy design. In: Dias Soares C, Milne J, Ashiabor H, Deketelaere K (eds) Critical issues in environmental taxation, vol. VIII. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 277–295
Copeland BR, Taylor MS (1994) North-south trade and the environment. Q J Econ 109(3):755–787
Cremer H, Gahvari F (2001) Second-best taxation of emissions and polluting goods. J Public Econ 80:169–197
Cremer H, Gahvari F, Ladoux N (1998) Externalities and optimal taxation. J Public Econ 70:343–364
DeNavas-Walt C, Proctor BD, Smith JC (2012) Income, poverty, and health insurance coverage in the United States: 2011. U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Reports, pp 60–243
Dissou Y, Siddiqui MS (2014) Can carbon taxes be progressive? Energy Econ 42:88–100
Ekins P (1999) European environmental taxes and charges: recent experience, issues and trends. Ecol Econ 31:39–62
Engel E (1857) Die Productions-und Consumtionsverhältnisse des Königreichs Sachsen. Zeitschrift des sächsischen Statistischen Bureaus des Innern 8 and 9, 1–54
Flues F, Thomas A (2015) The distributional effects of energy taxes: preliminary report. OECD Taxation Working Papers (23)
Fullerton D, Heutel G (2007) The general equilibrium incidence of environmental taxes. J Public Econ 91:571–591
Fullerton D, Heutel G (2010) Analytical general equilibrium effects of energy policy on output and factor prices. B E J Econ Anal Policy 10(2):1–24
Fullerton D, Hong I, Metcalf GE (2001) A tax on output of the polluting industry is not a tax on pollution. The importance of hitting the target. In: Carraro C, Metcalf GE (eds) Behavioral and distributional effects of environmental policy. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 13–44
Fullerton D, Metcalf GE (2001) Environmental controls, scarcity rents, and pre-existing distortions. J Public Econ 80:249–267
Fullerton D, Monti H (2013) Can pollution tax rebates protect low-wage earners? J Environ Econ Manag 66(3):539–553
Goulder LH (1995) Environmental taxation and the double dividend: a reader’s guide. Int Tax Public Finance 2(2):157–183
Goulder LH, Parry IW, Williams RC III, Burtraw D (1999) The cost-effectiveness of alternative instruments for environmental protection in a second-best setting. J Public Econ 72:329–360
Grainger CA, Kolstad CD (2010) Who pays a price on carbon? Environ Resour Econ 46(3):359–376
Jacobs B, De Mooij RA (2015) Pigou meets Mirrlees: on the irrelevance of tax distortions for the second-best Pigouvian tax. J Environ Econ Manag 71:90–108
Jacobs B, van der Ploeg F (2010) Precautionary climate change policies and optimal redistribution. OxCarre Research Paper 49
Kaplow L (2004) On the (ir)relevance of distribution and labor supply distortion to government policy. J Econ Perspect 18(4):159–175
Kaplow L (2012) Optimal control of externalities in the presence of income taxation. Int Econ Rev 53(2):487–509
Klenert D, Mattauch L (2016) How to make a carbon tax reform progressive: the role of subsistence consumption. Econ Lett 138:100–103
Kumhof M, Rancière R, Winant P (2015) Inequality, leverage, and crises. Am Econ Rev 105(3):1217–1245
Levinson A, O’Brien J (2015) Environmental Engel curves. NBER Working Paper Series 20914
Ligthart JE, van der Ploeg F (1999) Environmental policy, public goods and the marginal cost of public funds. Environ Resour Econ 13:187–207
Marrero GA, Rodríguez JG (2013) Inequality of opportunity and growth. J Dev Econ 104:107–122
Mirrlees J (1971) An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. Rev Econ Stud 38(2):175–208
OECD (2011) Divided we stand: why inequality keeps rising. OECD Publishing, Paris
Piketty T (2014) Capital in the twenty-first century. Harvard University Press, Cambridge
Rosenthal RE (2014) GAMS a user’s guide. GAMS Development Corporation, Washington
Sandmo A (1975) Optimal taxation in the presence of externalities. Swed J Econ 77(1):86–98
Sterner T (2011) Fuel taxes and the poor: the distributional effects of gasoline taxation and their implications for climate policy. RFF Press, New York
Thurow LC (1971) The income distribution as a pure public good. Q J Econ 85(2):327–336
Wier M, Birr-Pedersen K, Jacobsen HK, Klok J (2005) Are \({\rm CO}_2\) taxes regressive? Evidence from the Danish experience. Ecol Econ 52(2):239–251
Acknowledgments
The authors thank three anonymous reviewers for their encouraging and helpful comments. We further thank Ulrike Kornek and Jan Siegmeier, as well as the participants of the 2015 GGKP, the 2015 EAERE and the 2016 Tinbergen Institute conferences for insightful discussions.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendix: First-Order Conditions of Households and Firms
Appendix: First-Order Conditions of Households and Firms
Households
By combining the households’ first-order conditions with their budget equation, the following explicit demand functions can be derived:
with
Firms Maximizing profits of both firms yields four first-order conditions:
with \(j \in \{C,D\}\).
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Klenert, D., Schwerhoff, G., Edenhofer, O. et al. Environmental Taxation, Inequality and Engel’s Law: The Double Dividend of Redistribution. Environ Resource Econ 71, 605–624 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-016-0070-y
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-016-0070-y
Keywords
- Environmental tax reform
- Double dividend
- Revenue recycling
- Inequality
- Distribution
- Non-homothetic preferences